In my first post about large and small scale climate change mitigation, I mentioned the carbon tax. The tax
is considered to be the main alternative to a cap-and-trade system.
Source |
What is it?
Carbon taxing involves adding a financial incentive to
cutting emissions: bodies, whether they be firms or households, are taxed for
each unit of greenhouse gas emitted, with more carbon-heavy fossil fuel
products levied by higher taxes (Lin and Li, 2011).
Does it work?
Lin and Li (2011) review the effect of carbon taxes in
reducing CO2 emissions in five of the countries they have been
implemented in (Denmark, Finland, the Netherlands, Norway and Sweden). The
authors state that there are two main positive impacts to carbon taxing:
(1) Promotion
of substitutes for fuel products, allowing for development of energy saving and
energy efficiency.
(2) Investment
into environmental and clean energy initiatives through the money saved from
the carbon tax.
However, there are some clear limitations of the method
too. A key one of these is economically-based, in that implementing the tax
will lead to increased costs for businesses and lower competitiveness. Another
is that the ability of the tax to actually mitigate emissions. Lin and Li (2011) argue that rather than leading to emission reductions, businesses could
just raise the prices of the their products or services, leading to customers
taking on the cost of tax. Carbon leakage could also increase, as carbon
intensive industries migrate from carbon taxing countries to other, more lenient
countries (Lin and Li, 2011).
The authors found that the carbon tax had differing
effects on mitigation depending on the country studied. In Finland, the tax has
reduced the growth of carbon emissions per capita by a statistically
significant amount. Denmark, Sweden and the Netherlands also experienced
reductions, but not by enough to be of significance statistically. In Norway,
an increase in per capita emissions was suggested, but again this was not
significant (Lin and Li, 2011). This disparity is likely in some part caused by
tax exemptions provided by all countries other than Finland, for example, for
the manufacturing industry. It is suggested by the authors that in order to
obtain the best results from a carbon tax, a single rate needs to implemented
rather than differential rates.
Carbon tax vs
cap-and-trade
As stated above, there is a large debate as to whether
carbon taxing or cap-and-trade offers the best opportunities for mitigating
emissions. Wittneben (2009) argues that the
European Union Emission -Trading System (EU ETS), one of the most prominent
cap-and-trade schemes (and discussed in this post), has ultimately failed at reducing
carbon emissions, despite leading to heavy governmental income. The author
states that because carbon taxes are negotiated at a national level, the
severity of the tax will factor in the political climate of the nation itself,
leading to a theoretically-limitless level of emission reductions. This is
opposed to a cap on emissions, which also serves as a cap on reductions. Obviously,
this is an argument based more on theory than stone-cold facts, as seen by the
effectiveness of the carbon tax in the study by Lin and Li (2011).
Another key argument between the two are background
financials, which were studied by Carl and Fedor (2016). Wittneben (2009)
suggests that a carbon tax rather than cap-and-trade would lead to more capital
being available for green initiatives; however, Carl and Fedor (2016) argue
that this might not be the case. Analysing $28.3 billion that is currently generated
by 40 countries via “carbon revenues”, they state that $7.8 billion of this
goes towards “green” spending. Of the money collected from cap-and-trade, 70%
is directed towards “green” spending, compared to carbon taxes, in which 72% of
the income goes to government general funds instead. There is more complexity
to the argument than this however, as carbon taxes have the ability to generate
more capital than cap-and-trade Carl and Fedor (2016).
Cleetus (2011) offers a potential solution encompassing
both methods, called the price collar. The hybrid focusses on capping emissions
whilst also setting a minimum and maximum price for emission allowances. This
method would not set a carbon price or a specific cap on emissions, but would
provide bounds in which both of these could occur (Cleetus, 2011). Setting the
maximum and minimum prices is a challenge as it must promote the use of
low-carbon alternatives but not cause significant economic derailment.
A really good article published on the Guardian from a few years ago covers all three of these methods of mitigation. It is
clear that economic methods such as these offer a great opportunity for
emission reductions, but they have to be carefully selected for each country.
Finally, for an easy explanation of carbon taxing (using
chickens), and a quick comparison of it to cap-and-trade, see the video below:
No comments:
Post a Comment